Those frozen money markets

If you wanted to know a bit more about the mechanics of those frozen money markets, there are worse places to start but here. The article also explains the problems the inter-bank money market is experiencing, and how difficult it is for the Fed to deal with that. From the article, it can be shown why the British approach is so much better.

Inside the Credit Crisis: How the Fed’s Efforts to Lower the Fed Funds Rate May Leave it Powerless to Stop the Financial Meltdown
By Shah Gilani
Contributing Editor
Money Morning

  • “The truth? You can’t handle the truth.”
  • The truth is, the U.S. Federal Reserve does not directly control the Federal Funds rate, and its efforts to reduce the benchmark rate from 2.0% to 1.5% may do more damage than good – though for reasons you’d never guess. Attempts to lower the Fed Funds rate could irreparably damage Fed credibility and may actually narrow the Fed’s credit-crisis-management options.
  • The Fed Funds rate is the interest rate that banks charge one another for overnight loans. Under normal circumstances, the Fed Funds rate is the central bank’s primary and most effective tool in influencing interest rates. But the current market situation is anything but normal.
  • Contrary to what most people think, the Fed Funds rate is a “target;” it is not an absolute number that anyone actually has to follow. The central bank’s policymaking arm, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), resulting principally from its deliberations on the outlook for inflation, and secondarily the general state of the economy, raises and lowers interest rates throughout the financial system and the economy by targeting the Fed Funds rate.
  • Before the U.S. financial markets opened on Wednesday, Fed policymakers, headed by Chairman Ben S. Bernanke, announced that the central bank was lowering the Fed Funds rate half a percentage point to 1.5%. The idea is that, the lower a bank’s cost of money actually is, the cheaper the rate at which it can lend to others and still maintain a decent profit margin [For a complete discussion of cost of funds, and of the overall lending process, take a look at yesterday’s Money Morning report on the commercial paper market. The report is free of charge.]  Banks compete with each other to make loans. If they have lots of money to lend, they compete for business by lowering the interest rates they charge borrowers. The more money banks have, the lower interest rates go.
  • If the Fed lowers the rate at which banks borrow from one another, it stands to reason that banks will generally pass their lower cost of money along to borrowers. And that means the lower resulting interest rates will stimulate capital formation, production and consumption – and with it, the entire U.S. economy.
  • Well, at least that’s what’s supposed to happen. But here’s how it really works. Every major bank has a Fed Funds trading desk. The job of a bank’s Fed Funds trader is to buy or sell money overnight, or for longer periods. There are two reasons why banks buy and sell money:
  • * First, if a bank has money in its vault that it could – but hasn’t – lent out, that money does the bank no good just sitting there, not generating any interest income for the institution. So the bank’s trader actually calls around to other banks to see who wants to borrow some money.
  • * The second reason is actually far more critical and is always the bank’s first consideration: The Federal Reserve requires that banks keep at least a specified minimum of reserves in their vaults. That means that each and every evening, as the Fed tucks a bank in for the night, it always makes sure to ask: “Have you met your reserve requirements tonight?” If a bank has made a lot of loans that day, it may be short of cash to meet its reserve requirement ratio. If that happens, the bank’s Fed Funds trader calls other banks and borrows enough money to cover its reserve requirements.
  • Generally speaking, the interest that banks charge each other is close to what we know as the Fed Funds rate. If the Fed lowers the Fed Funds rate, theoretically the cost of money at which banks lend to one another is lower, too. In theory, then, if all banks have met their reserve requirements, and if they all have money to lend to each other overnight, and because money that doesn’t get lent out doesn’t make any interest, banks will lower interest rates for borrowers so that the money in their vaults is put to use and earns interest.
  • Here’s the rub. In order for the Fed to actually change the Fed Funds rate, it must itself go out into the market and buy and sell securities. The Fed executes open market operations through the New York Federal Reserve Bank, the most powerful of the 12 Federal Reserve Banks.
  • If the Fed wants, as it does now, to lower its Fed Funds target rate, it has to initiate the process. In order to add cash into the banking system, the New York Fed buys Treasuries from dealers and pays cash. The transaction is called a repurchase agreement, or “repo.” The result of this transaction, when done to the tune of billions of dollars, is that dealers now have billions in cash that they can deposit into banks. Since, banks theoretically now have a lot of cash to lend to one another overnight, they will lower the overnight rate that they charge each other.
  • The Fed must inject enough excess cash into banks’ vaults through its open-market repo operations to make sure the banks actually lower the overnight rates they charge one another until that rate approximates the central bank’s Fed Funds target rate. That’s the reality of how the target rateis reached.
  • But, as usual, there’s the story – and there’s the story behind the story.
  • Traditionally, when the Fed executes repurchase agreements, it buys U.S. Treasuries and pays cash for them. The Treasury securities the central bank buys becomes part of its balance sheet. Now, however, dealers and banks are loath to sell any Treasuries. Why? Because Treasuries are the only security on dealers’ and banks’ balance sheets whose actual worth they know. They’re not parting with them.
  • Because the Fed is determined to add liquidity by providing loans and easily marketable securities to banks and dealers through its discount window and term auction facility, it is already taking in all manner of other securities, including equities, against which the Fed is lending Treasuries from its own balance sheet. If the Fed wants to lower the Fed Funds rate, and dealers and banks aren’t going to sell it any Treasuries, the central bank will have to take in other securities (toxic junk) as collateral against the cash that it hopes to inject into the banking system through its repurchase agreements.
  • Just how depleted and how damaged the Fed’s balance sheet may become is a major concern. But, that’s not the immediate problem.
  • Lowering the Fed Funds rate may not work at all.
  • Just because the Fed floods banks with cash doesn’t mean that banks will lend each other money – at the targeted Fed Funds rate, or at any rate. Banks are all fearful of each other – I’m talking on a worldwide basis – they are increasingly hoarding cash as a cushion against their own upcoming losses. They’re facing increasing weakness in their commercial-loan and commercial mortgage-backed securities inventories (the next shoe to drop). And banks are increasingly facing heightened exposure to leveraged loan portfolios on their books that they can’t off-load, and rapidly deteriorating credit-card-based securities and portfolios.
  • If the Federal Reserve is unable to facilitate overnight-bank lending, and is unable to actually lower the Fed Funds rate to its target rate of 1.5%, what will that do to its credibility? It is devastating that we have no trust in our banks; but if we also lose trust in our central-bank firefighter’s ability to quell the financial conflagration, the darkening skies may make the last three weeks seem only partly cloudy.
  • The Fed and the U.S. Treasury Department have done a good job in addressing, publicly, what needs to be done. Unfortunately, they have both made the cardinal sin of actually showing us their hands, when they should have played their aces earlier and controlled the game.
  • Now the whole world is watching.
  • And since we know the hand we’re all playing, it’s only a matter of what cards are turned over that will determine our future.
  • On Monday, I’ll show you the Treasury’s hand and tell you why that game is already lost.
  • We need to drop these games, reshuffle the cards and play this out as the “house” with greater odds in our favor. It can be done by Election Day, but we’re going to have to take the politics out of the game – once and for all.
  • Can we do it?

Now, why is that British plan much better? Because it just guarantees inter-bank lending, and recapitalizes the banks, in addition to providing liquidity.